:
Happy Monday morning, everyone. Welcome to meeting number 127 of the House of Commons Standing Committee on Industry and Technology.
Today’s meeting is taking place in a hybrid format, pursuant to the Standing Orders.
Pursuant to the order of reference of Wednesday, February 7, 2024, the committee is commencing consideration of Bill .
Today we have Mr. Jagmeet Singh with us.
Mr. Singh, thank you for joining us to present your bill.
Before we begin, I would ask all participants to consult the cards on the table for guidelines on the use of earpieces. This is for the health and safety of all participants, especially our interpreters.
Without further ado, I yield the floor to Mr. Singh.
I am extremely happy to be here. Thank you for giving me the opportunity to present my thoughts on my bill.
[English]
I know competition is not a topic that a lot of Canadians think is relevant in their lives, but I believe this is fundamentally important for Canadians. I think of two examples for why this is such an important bill: food, and cellphone and Internet fees.
When we talk about food in our country right now, we're up against a really serious situation, as you know, Mr. Chair. Canadians are faced with record food bank usage. One out of four Canadians are skipping meals because the cost of food is so expensive. Canadians know that when they go into a grocery store and they're paying the highest fees ever for their groceries, on the other end of that, they have corporate CEOs who are making record profits for their corporations. They're being gouged and ripped off. That has to stop.
We know this is not something that Canadians are unfamiliar with. Back in 2018, the large corporate grocery stores and bread producers worked together to rip off Canadians with the bread price-fixing scheme. We know the cost of that was significant. Canadians were ripped off to the tune of $5 billion, but the biggest fine that was levied for one of the major players of this bread price-fixing scheme, Canada Bread Company, got a fine of $50 million.
In the scheme of things, when the collective benefit they accrued was $5 billion that they ripped off Canadians, a $50 million fine is a slap on the wrist. That has to stop.
We know that protecting consumers and fighting back against corporate greed will lower the cost of food and the cost of living for Canadians.
The other area where we know this is significant is when it comes to cellphone and Internet fees. We pay amongst the highest cellphone and Internet fees in the world. It's no surprise that as a result of merger after merger, there is a massive concentration. Just three cellphone and Internet providers make up the majority of cellphone and Internet services in our country. They are Rogers, Bell and Telus.
We recently saw a merger, which only makes things worse. The merger between Rogers and Shaw is only going to mean higher costs for consumers and fewer options. Again, this is going to make life more unaffordable. It's another example of corporate greed.
That merger should have never happened. My bill would allow for measures to ensure that doesn't happen in the future or it makes it a lot more difficult.
We know the cost of living is up and we know that corporate greed is driving it up. My bill hopes to prevent that from continuing. Stopping large corporations from ripping off consumers will lower prices for Canadians.
I believe the role of government is to strengthen and protect consumer's rights and protect consumers against exploitation. That's what I hope to do with my bill.
I want to break down some specifics to hopefully lay the foundation for your questions.
Since the introduction of my bill, we have been able to force the government to make significant changes to their existing bills to protect consumers. I want to go over those changes that have been made. These are changes to Bill and Bill .
New Democrats put forward amendments to specifically increase penalties for anti-competitive behaviour and to make it easier for the Competition Bureau to go after these large corporations when they rip off Canadians.
We also specifically changed definitions to include price gouging as an offence.
We also ensured that the Competition Bureau is able to initiate investigations so it can actually identify when problems are happening, compel documents and go after corporate greed.
There have been changes now, because of what we forced the government to do, that would make it harder for mergers such as the Rogers-Shaw merger.
There are three things that are outstanding—or fundamentally two main areas.
One is the bread price-fixing that I spoke about. That remains something that is not covered in the way that it should be by the Liberal government. They've refused to put in place strengthened penalties.
If corporations are doing the crime, then they have to pay the fine. What we want to see happen is that, in the cases of large corporations working together to rip off Canadians, there should be severe and significant fines. That's something that's missing in this bill.
We think there should be certain mergers that, if they hurt Canadians, should be banned outright. Not an assessment of whether this will hurt or not hurt, or whether they should go ahead or not. If they reach a certain level, they should be banned outright. That's a change this government was unwilling to do.
I would point out that I believe the government can be a force for good for Canadians. It can fight corporate greed and make life affordable.
For decades, the Liberals and Conservatives have ignored corporate greed. They have purposely ignored strengthening the rights of consumers and ignored the tools that the Competition Bureau needs to take on corporate greed. I hope to change that with this bill. We have done some significant changes with amendments and this will finish the job.
:
—you're talking to the competition critic, the shadow minister, for the Conservative Party, because our leader decided that competition was important enough to put someone in this position. When we talk about where you could have been, you're in another position. You could have stopped the government from approving these three mergers that have hurt Canadians.
We say that it's a walking contradiction. You're standing up for these corporations, which have only gotten bigger—
Mr. Jagmeet Singh: I'm not standing up for them; I'm opposing them.
Mr. Ryan Williams:—since you've been in power, and consumers have less power. We're not seeing the prices come down. We're not seeing competition. You presented a bill, and we presented lots of changes. You and I both proposed a change to the efficiencies defence, which this government stole from us.
You're not standing up for Canadians, and Canadians feel that you've sold them out. They feel that you're not standing up to the corporations. They feel that they're not going to do it, so people only trust the actions....
Mr. Singh, the other change that we're pushing for in Canada is open banking. If we want to talk about taking a chunk out of the banks in Canada, open banking would do that. In the U.K., when open banking was implemented, it saved the average person in the U.K. $400 a year. There are no transactional fees, no monthly fees and no overdraft fees with open banking, and that's with only 14% market share.
This government took six years to bring legislation forward. They picked a regulator and only gave them a pittance, $1 million, to get the regulations in. This regulator, FCAC, was just in front of a Senate committee.
Do you know how many of the 27,000 complaints they have answered since 2019? Can you just tell me the number?
:
Thanks, Chair, and thanks to Mr. Singh for being here today.
It's kind of ironic hearing the Conservatives talk about saving $400 per year when they won't support saving families money on child care, dental care, pharmacare or feeding hungry kids, or a Canada disability benefit, or, or, or. The list goes on, including the Canada child benefit, and many more.
Mr. Singh, I know you are saying that you forced us to do certain things. Obviously I will have to disagree on that, because the Government of Canada has put forward multiple rounds of revisions to the Competition Act—Bill, Bill , and Bill —and I think the collaborative efforts of working together with the NDP on some of those changes have been very productive. I think we should all take that approach when doing our parliamentary work, because what we're really here for is to serve Canadians.
We know competition in the market. More competition means more options and better prices. We've been saying that since day one. I think we may beg to differ on some aspects, but that's the government's standpoint.
Mr. Singh, I want to take a step back. I'm interested in your approach to competition reform—and here I know you're a former defence attorney and a defender of the Charter of Rights and Freedoms.
Would you say that you appreciate the principles of natural justice that are protected under the charter?
:
I think I know where the member is going with this line of questioning.
As a lawyer, I can tell you that what we've found is that giving judges pure discretion when it comes to setting sentences has resulted in the case that I gave you of the $5 billion, which large corporations have ripped off Canadians with bread pricing. The biggest fine that a judge levied in that case was $50 million, which is a slap on the wrist if you think about $5 billion in net revenue.
What I'm hoping to establish are some guidelines for judges. Judges follow guidelines. They're going to follow jurisprudence. The highest fine was $50 million. That's not going to be a significant deterrent.
What we've said is that the judge should be able to use deterrence to the extent of 10% of the revenue of a company. In the case of Loblaws, with $60 billion in revenue, the judge should be able to impose a fine of $6 billion. That is deterrence. Without having guidelines, judges won't go further than jurisprudence, and right now $50 million is the highest fine that's ever been levied. It's far too low.
I just want to be clear. While we were able to force the government to bring in changes to anti-competitive behaviour, the government refused to bring in those changes to the collusion or conspiracy or the price-fixing, and the price-fixing is what I'm talking about with the bread price-fixing.
That scenario that we have evidence of happened in 2018. The Liberals and, frankly, the Conservatives are unwilling to go after that price-fixing. That's what I'm proposing to do in this bill that is outstanding, to address price-fixing or that conspiracy, or when corporations work together to rip off Canadians. That's where we need penalties that are severe. Those penalties are not in the current government legislation. That's what my bill would do, and that would significantly protect consumers.
Welcome to the committee, Mr. Singh. It is a pleasure to see you.
Congratulations on introducing your bill.
Obviously, you have focused on grocery stores, since that is the issue of the year. We understand that it is important, but your bill would change the competition rules for all industries, so I would like to talk to you, as my Conservative colleague did, about the open banking system.
You know that the banks today are having to become manufacturers of financial products, and there are apps where customers go to buy them and use them. So there needs to be legislation and regulations to regulate all of that, actually. You know that the budget, which you supported, contained an intention to regulate the open banking system. You also know, since you are a very well-informed man, that our biggest financial institution in Quebec, Desjardins, is owned by the Government of Quebec.
The government's bill seems to contain the intention to impose a framework and hold a gun to Desjardins' temple and simply tell it to choose between adhering to the federal framework and being isolated on its own. There seems to have been no coordination with the Government of Quebec in order to harmonize all of this.
What is your position? Would you be prepared to support a bill about the open banking system for which there was no coordination with the Government of Quebec in order to take the biggest employer in Quebec and our biggest financial institution into consideration?
Would you support a bill like that?
:
We will await your thoughts on that. Thank you.
Many of the provisions of your bill have already been applied, since they are part of bills that were passed earlier, such as Bills and . However, part of it would still add a lot of constraints on competition authorities.
Essentially, with the legislative changes that have been made so far, not only must the competition bureau look for efficiency gains before authorizing a transaction, but it must now also be possible to prove that consumers have benefitted from the efficiency gains. Your bill then adds a constraint associated with market structure, not the consequence of a merger. If the combined market share resulting from a merger exceeds 60%, it will be prohibited, and if it is between 30% and 60%, there will be an investigation, if I understand correctly.
What would happen, for example, in cases where there is what is called a natural monopoly, in remote regions? There are grocery chains in very remote regions that have trouble staying open, and if they do not merge in order to take over the market, they will go bankrupt and people will no longer have food.
Do you know that the inflexibility of your bill would prevent people from eating, in some regions? Have you thought about that?
:
Thank you, Mr. Chair. It's a pleasure to be here.
Thank you, Mr. Singh, for coming.
I find it curious that my Conservative colleagues have forgotten their own history. I remember the days of the Conservatives under Peter MacKay and David Orchard, the takeover and so forth, and even under the Harper administration, when they put just enough members in the House of Commons to oppose or turn over a government because they didn't have them in there. They went to the lobby like they did the other time, just this past session, instead of actually taking it on and trying to be constructive.
I think this bill is important because, despite the differences at the table about things, we can always find reasons not to do it.
This committee, however, actually has a good record of bipartisanship and putting on record some of these issues. With the grocery store chains in particular, it was this committee that first brought the CEOs here, because not only were they doing the bread price-fixing, but they also ended the pandemic pay the very same day, across the board.
Could you elaborate a bit more about the issue of bread pricing? It is a basic staple of human life that we use in Canada.
How might this bill have affected the Rogers-Shaw merger that went ahead? Had we had this protection, what would the potential outcome of that have been?
:
Thank you very much for the question.
Again, fundamentally, I can't think of something that's more important for Canadians than being able to buy food. It's a necessity. Everyone needs to do it. What we're seeing very clearly, if we look across the country, is that when Canadians go to buy their groceries, they're getting ripped off when they go through checkout. They know it. When Canadians were asked this question, they said very clearly that they felt that corporate greed was a major reason that food prices were up.
This bill directly targets that. We're going to directly target the large corporate grocery stores in our country—the Loblaws, the Metros, the Sobeys, the Walmarts, the Costcos—and go after them directly to say that they cannot rip off consumers. This bill would provide additional protection.
The specific area that's missing, and that I pointed out to the Liberals, is that while we were able to get them to change the penalties on anti-competitive behaviour, they've refused to put in the strengthened penalties on conspiracy or when large corporations work together to rip off Canadians. The bread price-fixing scenario, which I've alluded to, was that the large corporate grocery stores and large corporate bread producers got together and jacked up the price of bread. They were found guilty of doing so. As a result, they received fines. The heftiest fine was on Canada Bread Company. It was only $50 million. In the context of how much they made and how much they ripped off Canadians, it was a slap on the wrist.
Our bill provides clear guidelines for judges to impose stricter and more severe penalties. We know that in Canada, as a common law country, the penalties will follow jurisprudence. Right now the precedent that's been set is $50 million. That's the highest fine. That is simply not high enough. We've provided a guideline for a judge of how high they can go. On what we've provided, two of them I think are very significant. One of them is 10% of the revenue of a company. For a company like Loblaws, which makes $60 billion, the fine can be as high as $6 billion. Giving a judge a clear guideline of how high they can go will allow us to have more severe penalties to deter these companies.
Another example of what we've allowed for is triple the benefit accrued. If collectively these corporations made $15 billion, then collectively a judge can impose a sanction of $15 billion in fines. That, again, is very serious deterrence. If a company knows they're going to have a jeopardy of billions of dollars in fines, they're not going to rip off Canadians. That's important.
You mentioned also the Rogers-Shaw merger. To be very clear, the Competition Bureau tried to stop it. We asked the minister directly to stop it. The Liberals refused to stop this merger, and they should have. That merger is bad for Canadians. It's going to be bad for competition. It's going to lower options and choices. It's going to increase prices.
Our bill, where we were able to force the government to include some of those measures, would ensure that if a merger results in more than 30% of the market share, there would be a very difficult process that the company would have to go through to prove that it would benefit Canadians or prove that it can benefit consumers. That's a very difficult threshold. They would not have been able to make that threshold proven in the case of the Rogers-Shaw merger.
In that merger case, it was almost 60%, but it didn't hit that threshold. If it were 60% or higher, then it would trigger an immediate ban of that merger, which is something we need to have. We need to have strict measures in place to prevent these oligopolies from being formed, because we're seeing the result of them. With corporate grocery stores, with telecommunications, Canadians have less choice and higher costs, and it is ripping them off.
I know that the Liberals think, “Oh, gotcha moment”, because we on the opposition side here have been pushing against the tribunal on the privacy legislation and offering solutions for it. One of the issues we have with that is the mere fact that the Competition Bureau tribunal is actually suing our Competition Bureau itself. It's going to cost Canadians money and also confidence in the Competition Bureau, in my opinion. That's one of the reasons we don't find a tribunal to be one of the best things in the place.
Your bill looks to amend the tribunal, to some degree, by actually stopping it from being able to sue back the Competition Bureau. Can you elaborate on that? It's absolutely absurd that we would actually have a position of the Competition Bureau basically not only overturned and overruled but then punished, and punishing Canadians because they stood up for the right things and they did the right professional job.
Thank you, Mr. Singh, for being here.
You spoke a lot in your opening, obviously, about food prices. It's a main driver of this initiative. However, over nine years, the NDP has voted for every single budget that has put forward, and Canadians are more miserable and hungrier than ever. For example, lettuce is up 94% in that time, onions 69% and cabbage 70%—since your deal with the Liberals. A Dalhousie study by “The Food Professor”, as he calls himself, shows that carbon taxes are increasing wholesale food prices by 34%.
My question is simple: Will you finally admit that carbon taxes increase the price of food?
:
Well, a couple of things are just false in that comment.
In nine years, we have not supported every budget. That's not true.
In terms of the costs that Canadians are going through, Canadians were asked this very same question: What do you think is a major driver of your groceries?
Mr. Rick Perkins: [Inaudible—Editor]
Mr. Jagmeet Singh: Canadians were asked, and they answered that the major driver that's pushing up the cost of their food is corporate greed.
We also had an investigation. We had the Competition Bureau look into this, and it is very clear that corporations are ripping off Canadians. In fact, economists have made it clear—
Thank you, Mr. Singh, for being here today.
I'm not going to attempt to put the focus on the politics of the life that we live here in Ottawa, nor the parties that we represent. I want to put the focus on people and fairness.
When the government introduced Bill and Bill , that's in fact what we did: We put the emphasis on people and on fairness with respect to competition reform. To some extent I think that's what you're trying to do here, too, and I appreciate that.
With that said, through those bills we have established strengthened market studies and the power to compel. We've clamped down on anti-competitive behaviour and cross-industry collaboration. We've removed the efficiencies defence, strengthened the right to repair, strengthened anti-greenwashing provisions, strengthened merger review and cracked down on unfair pricing practices—including drip pricing—as well as strengthening monetary penalties.
I've read your PMB, and I appreciate the intent, but also appreciate what we've accomplished through Bill and Bill .
What I really want to do is get a bit more granular, Mr. Singh, and drill down on the business part of it, not the politics of it.
You mentioned some of the missing elements of those bills. Correct me if I'm wrong, but you said they were missing strengthened penalties. Therefore, my first question is: What more strengthened penalties do you want to have, over and above what are identified in both of those bills? My second question is whether certain mergers should be banned if they reach a certain level.
Can we get a bit more granular on that? Quite frankly, my intent is to take something away from this discussion and accomplish what you, we, the committee—I would only assume all of us—want to accomplish with respect to being fair, and again, attaching it to the people whom we represent.
I think it's an important reflection to just bring it back to whom this bill is about. This bill is about people. It's about people who are going to the grocery store and getting ripped off. It's about people who are paying cellphone bills and Internet fees that are among the highest in the world, and knowing that Canadians need some relief. This bill is about protecting people, protecting consumers and putting in stiffer penalties.
While I agree we've been able to push for amendments that have addressed a number of changes, including the ability of the Competition Bureau to investigate examples of anti-competitive behaviour, including stiffer penalties when there is anti-competitive behaviour, the piece that's missing is a piece that I spoke about. It is when we look at one of the most glaring examples of large corporations ripping off Canadians, it's when they colluded or worked together to jack up the price of bread. That is termed “price-fixing”. It could also be referred to as a "conspiracy". It's also referred to as "collusion". That behaviour, when large corporations work together to rip off Canadians, that specific area was not addressed by the Liberals. We had pushed for changes. Those changes were not accepted.
What we've included in my bill is addressing the specific matter that I pointed out—that in one of the most egregious examples of collusion, bread price-fixing, the highest penalty was $50 million on Canada Bread Company. That $50 million is barely a slap on the wrist for that corporation, given the total amount of revenue that all partners in that collusion were able to accrue. The amount that they ripped off Canadians was tallied at $5 billion.
What my bill does is provide guidelines to a judge that in a case as severe as that, here are some areas where they can go. They can go to 10% of the revenue of a company. You can go to triple the benefit they accrued. That is severe deterrence. Those are severe penalties that would deter these companies from ripping people off. That's the specific measure.
The other measure that I've included is in the case where a merger would result in 60% or more of a market share. In that case, it should be immediately banned.
:
I understand the need to reduce the threshold to 30% from 35% and do a study. On the 60% threshold, I think this is an aspect of the legislation that will probably never have any teeth.
I have one last question for you, Mr. Singh. My time is running out—you know what it is like not to be part of the official opposition.
I would like to talk about Glentel. As you know, Bell and Rogers have formed a joint venture, and it is soon going to have a monopoly on the sale of cellphone plans in Loblaws grocery stores. Your bill tackles market structure, but it seems to me that even after Bills and , there are still behaviours that seem anti-competitive but are still allowed.
What is your opinion about this business model? What do you think about the idea of two competitors forming a joint venture and holding the monopoly in a big grocery chain?
Do you think these are anti-competitive practices? Do you think we should go even further than what Bills C-56 and C-59 have already done?
Actually, I'm glad this point was raised because, as New Democrats, we were opposed to a number of these takeovers. A good review of some of the ones that took place, if we remember, is that we actually lost Future Shop to Best Buy. We opposed that. We lost Zellers. It was taken over by Target, and then Target even abandoned Canada, after Zellers actually had a union and above average wages and benefits for their workers, and was blown out of the Canadian market altogether. Because of that, we opposed it. Another one, which is important for Quebec, was the Rona takeover by Lowe's, which we opposed. The market share you mentioned, 60%, is actually getting ahead of things. I appreciate that because, when you look what's left over in the market, we have Telus, Bell, Rogers, Videotron and Cogeco, so we have those as the major pieces that are left in the puzzle, and a 60% threshold is possible if we don't get in front. Perhaps you can elaborate about how, yes, we can't predict the future, but we can send signals to the corporations that we just can't be treated like a colony anymore, in terms of Canadian consumers.
:
It's a great example. I touched on it in the previous question, but it gives me a chance to elaborate on it.
In terms of the 60% threshold—not just in telecommunications, but also in grocery stores—with the massive amount of market share that each of these corporations now hold, if there are any additional mergers, we would see that 60% threshold being hit. The message we're sending with this bill is that, no, that's not allowed. You cannot merge in such a manner that's going to hurt Canadians.
These mergers will be banned outright. It would stop these companies from even considering those type of mergers. I think it's very important, sadly, given how concentrated things are at this point.
As you mentioned in your question, Mr. Masse, there are already such significant concentrations in the telecommunications market that any additional merger would easily hit that threshold. We want to say that, no, that shouldn't happen.
I appreciate, Mr. Masse, you going through the history of all the mergers that New Democrats have opposed. We can see clearly that again and again both Liberals and Conservatives have allowed these mergers to move forward. They have had the opportunity to oppose them and have not. That has been bad for Canadians. That has done injury to Canadians.
That's why I'm putting forward a bill right now that would actually stop this from happening.
:
Mr. Singh, I want to go back to the cellphone question.
After the Rogers-Shaw merger, I asked you if you knew how much the prices went up and how much the wireless revenue per customer went up. I didn't get an answer.
It's 1% for the year on already the highest prices at a time when this government promised that it would reduce prices by 50%. Actually, it said it did that.
At the end of the day, we're seeing a government that's promising something that it's not then delivering. We're seeing that you're standing behind them and not doing enough to force them. You have the power, sir.
Even when you were at the heritage committee last week, you had the Bell CEO, Mirko Bibic, in front of you. You didn't even ask him a question about the new Loblaws rates and No Name rates that are being offered through Bell.
What is your red line, sir, in order to hold this government up to stop mergers that are hurting Canadians?
Like you say, it's not just about bills or asking a question in Parliament, but what is your red line to hold this government up to ensure you're standing up for Canadians? We've not seen that at all.
:
Great. Thank you, Chair, and thank you to Mr. Singh for appearing before the committee.
I want to cover the overlap between what the government has presented and this bill. Obviously, we passed major competition reforms with Bill . It empowers regulators to hold the companies accountable, and it does stand up for Canadians. We gave more power to the Competition Bureau to conduct more effective investigations. We made it easier to block mergers that are not in the best interest of Canadians and took action against collaborators that stifle competition and reduce consumer choice.
If there were something lacking in Bill , I think that was largely covered by Bill , whose amendments have resulted in a more modern and effective competition law. Among other things, they help prevent harmful mergers and anti-competitive collaborations, and they hold the large firms accountable.
I want to talk about your testimony in response to Mr. Badawey's questioning. You talked about how, perhaps, what your bill brings is more of a focus on price-fixing and on penalties, but then I look at Bill , which is from 2022 and says:
Division 15 of Part 5 amends the Competition Act to enhance the Commissioner of Competition's investigative powers, criminalize wage fixing and related agreements, increase maximum fines and administrative monetary penalties, clarify that incomplete price disclosure is a false or misleading representation, expand the definition of anti-competitive conduct, allow private access to the Competition Tribunal to remedy an abuse of dominance and improve the effectiveness of the merger notification requirements and other provisions.
When I look at all these bills in combination, it largely seems that what Bill is proposing is already covered.
What are your comments on that?
:
I would first point out that the changes in both Bill and Bill were amendments specifically brought in by the NDP to address higher penalties and anti-competitive behaviour. Those amendments were successful, and we're happy that we were able to push for those things.
The same approach to anti-competitive behaviour is not being mirrored by the approach to price-fixing. It is not the same approach. Even when you cited Bill , it doesn't have the same rigour when approaching anti-competitive behaviour as when approaching price-fixing.
Specifically, when I talk about price-fixing, we're talking about the situation when corporations collude, work together or have a conspiracy to set prices higher together. Specifically what I'm referring to is the bread price-fixing. That matter, the bread price-fixing, has not been addressed. It is one of the most egregious recent examples of large corporations ripping off Canadians. That specific matter has yet to be addressed. What I'm calling for are clear penalties that address that matter. That is the area where we suggested amendments that the Liberals turned down.
The Liberals have not shown a willingness to go after what has been the most egregious recent example of corporations working together to rip off Canadians, which is when they colluded to rip off Canadians with the price of bread. That's what I'm going after, and that has not specifically been addressed.
We are setting a guideline for penalties to address the matter. The $50 million fine, which was the highest fine on one of the most egregious cases, was far too low. It was barely a slap on the wrist. The guidelines that we're providing would give judges serious remedies to put in place a penalty as severe as 10% of the revenue of the corporation, which, in the case of a company like Loblaws, would be $6 billion. That's what I'm talking about when I talk about remedies.
:
I'm not a competition lawyer, but insofar as I have knowledge of this area, price-fixing is a type of anti-competitive behaviour.
We are both lawyers. From my read of these bills in collaboration, they largely do cover the same thing. There are some enhancements that Bill brings, but I think the government has really worked hard in this area over the years. These three bills speak to that.
I want to ask about the efficiencies exemption. Your bill will repeal the efficiencies exemption, but then it places the efficiency and competition comparison as a factor that could be considered in the substantial lessening or prevention of a competition test.
Maybe an unintended consequence of this is that your bill would still allow anti-competitive mergers to withstand the challenge on the basis of efficiencies, but on a discretionary basis.
Was that the intent of your bill?
:
The intent is to get rid of a loophole that allows corporations to merge, even though it hurts Canadians.
If there is an amendment that would further strengthen the bill to protect Canadians against abuses, I'm always open to hearing that. As it stands, this is a matter that's not been addressed and needs to be addressed.
I do want to reiterate that, while there are three bills, and while New Democrats have forced this government to bring in strong amendments that would strengthen protection, it still does not address the specific nature of a conspiracy or a collusion. The anti-competitive behaviour matters that are addressed do not directly address what happened with the bread price-fixing. That is what I'm trying to get at in this bill, the most egregious case and one thing that Canadians can still recall. Canadians remember when the 2018 ruling found that these companies had colluded and had worked together to rip them off, the penalties were so minor that they were barely slaps on the wrist. That has to be remedied.
That's why this bill is very explicit and clear in addressing price-fixing, those collusion scenarios, those conspiracy scenarios, where large corporations rip off Canadians.
:
Colleagues, I would ask you to take your places so we do not lose too much of the scheduled time.
[English]
Colleagues, I'll ask you to take your seats. We're resuming the meeting.
Before we go to the witness testimony on Bill , you've received a copy of the budget for the study of Bill C-352, which is $10,500. It was circulated. Do I have unanimous consent to adopt it?
(Motion agreed to)
The Chair: Thank you very much.
[Translation]
Thank you for joining us for this first of the committee's meetings on Bill C‑352. With us is Pierre Larouche, professor of law and innovation in the faculty of law at the Université de Montréal.
Welcome, professor.
We also welcome, from the competition bureau of Canada, Matthew Boswell, commissioner of competition, and Anthony Durocher, deputy commissioner, competition promotion branch.
Last, we welcome, from the Canadian Bar Association, Antonio Di Domenico, secretary, Competition Law and Foreign Investment Section.
[English]
Thank you very much for joining us.
Without further ado, I'll yield the floor to Professor Larouche for five minutes.
The floor is yours.
Thank you for this invitation to appear before your committee.
Allow me to introduce myself briefly. I am a full professor of law and innovation in the law faculty at the Université de Montréal. I have 30 years' experience in competition law and economic governance, partly in private practice, but mainly as a professor of competition law in Europe. I taught in Europe for 15 years. At the College of Europe, I taught a number of European Commission officials who work on major competition cases. I taught American competition law during a sabbatical year at Northwestern University. For the last seven years I have been at the Université de Montréal, where I continue to work in this field. I am back in touch with Canadian law.
It is a pleasure to speak to you this morning. I would like to start with a slightly theoretical comment on all of this. There are a lot of good intentions behind the proposed amendments to the Competition Act, such as Bill , which has been passed, and Bill , which is under consideration. However, if we compare Canadian law to the law of other member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, the OECD, it stands out in two regards: first, the act is very long and very complex; second, the institutional framework is deficient. As a result, Canadian competition law is weak and difficult to enforce. The defendants, the corporations, will be easily able to defend themselves, and they will generally succeed in avoiding enforcement.
Since the act is long and complex, it is my opinion that we have to stop adding details to it. Instead, we need to go back to broad principles, take clear broad policy positions, and give the commissioner and the competition bureau more room to do their work.
Regarding the institutional framework in Canada, the bureau should have decision-making powers the way it is done everywhere in Europe, even in the United Kingdom, and, in part, for the powers of the American authorities. I think that if we look at what has happened recently in Canadian law, especially with the merger between Rogers and Shaw, the tribunal was the main problem. It should have acted only as an appeal body or, even better, should do judicial review on the basis of a decision of the bureau.
I am now going to talk about the two more specific questions that concern you today regarding Bill C‑352, which Mr. Singh referred to earlier. Increasing penalties under section 45 is a good idea in itself, but again, this shows how complex the Canadian law is, forcing a choice between sections 45 and 90. Obviously, the penalties need to be high under section 45, but that is criminal law and it is not as easy. An appropriate penalty, as mentioned here, would be 10% of worldwide revenues. Ideally, if we look at the practice of the European Commission and the American authorities, the level of the penalty should be about the same as the level of the corporation's profit for it to really hurt; it is generally about 5% to 6% of revenues. By adopting a maximum penalty of 10%, Canada is in the right league, and that means that the penalties should easily amount to hundreds of millions of dollars.
However, regarding the second proposal, the market share thresholds for controlling concentrations, I think that is a reference point that is a bit outdated. It is preferable to have a good general test and let the bureau do its work. Market shares may cause errors in both directions. First, there may be the exceptional case of a merger with high market shares where it would still be possible to prove that it is good for consumers. Second, and most importantly, there are also mergers with lower market shares that may be harmful to consumers, for example where the two merging parties are close competitors in the market.
These are factors that are definitely part of the contemporary analysis of competition law and that cannot be addressed in terms of market share thresholds, which obviously create the illusion that the only problem arises out of horizontal mergers, when vertical mergers, or conglomerate mergers, can be just as problematic.
Those are my introductory comments.
Thank you again for hearing me today.
:
Good afternoon, Mr. Chair. Thank you for the invitation to appear before you today.
[Translation]
My name is Matthew Boswell and I am the commissioner of competition. With me is my colleague Anthony Durocher, who is the deputy director of the competition promotion branch.
We are pleased to be here today to discuss Bill . As a result of several pieces of legislation, competition policy in Canada is undergoing a generational upgrade. We are grateful to the members of this committee and other people who have particularly stressed the need to strengthen competition in the Canadian economy.
As you undoubtedly know, most of the important points in Bill have been incorporated into past and future legislation: Bills , and . Those amendments give effect to a large number of recommendations by the bureau and better harmonize our competition framework with the best international practices.
[English]
Just as competition in the marketplace forces firms to offer products and services that better meet consumer needs, competition in the marketplace for ideas leads to better public policies. In my view, the sponsors of Bill and other private members' bills introduced this session deserve credit for prompting substantial improvements to the Competition Act. These improvements include, among other things, a significant revamp of our abuse of dominance provisions, including stronger penalties, the addition of rebuttable structural presumptions in merger reviews and stronger remedies for anti-competitive mergers, the possibility for formal market studies to be initiated by the commissioner, and insulating the commissioner of competition from adverse cost awards at the Competition Tribunal.
By my count, there are only a few outstanding elements of Bill that have not been taken forward already in other legislation. In the grand scheme of competition law modernization that has taken place, the remaining issues are not of pressing concern, but certainly, some of them could further enhance the Competition Act. We would be happy to discuss those few elements.
There are also some aspects of the bill that would, in my view, represent a step backward, given prior reforms, such as the reintroduction of a cap on cartel fines. We would be happy, of course, to discuss those as well.
During our time today, or perhaps in a future appearance before this committee, it might also be productive to discuss what I often refer to as the elephant in the room in Canada. That is regulatory barriers to competition in this country.
The Competition Act is a foundational tool to protect and promote greater competition in Canada, but it is not the only tool. To build on the incredible progress made in modernizing the Competition Act, all of us in the public sector, at all levels of government, need to examine what more can be done to address the regulations and policies that hold back competition in Canada, often unintentionally. We know that Canada’s competitive intensity has decreased over the last two decades. It will take a whole-of-government approach to turn the tide, with the federal government working alongside municipal, provincial and territorial governments.
Increased competitiveness is key to tackling affordability challenges, improving consumer choice and fostering stronger, more inclusive growth over the long term and, importantly, addressing Canada’s pressing need for more productivity.
Competition policy in Canada is clearly having a moment. We need to seize that moment. There has never been a stronger consensus that Canada needs more competition. Now is the time for governments across Canada to work together to make competition a national economic priority.
[Translation]
In conclusion, the competition bureau is determined to apply the law in a transparent and evidence-based way. We have been unwavering in our efforts to implement the new and improved tools that Parliament has given us, and we will stay on this course.
Thank you for giving us the opportunity to appear before you today.
It will be our pleasure to answer your questions.
[English]
Thank you. We look forward to your questions.
I want to express appreciation on behalf of the CBA section for the invitation to appear today. Our members have significant experience advising a wide range of clients in competition matters. We appreciate the opportunity to be heard, so thank you for that.
By way of overview, many of the issues addressed in Bill have either been addressed in Bill , which received royal assent in December 2023, or contained in Bill , which is currently before the Senate. I would like to speak today regarding two proposals in Bill C-352. namely, the merger prohibition and structural presumption provisions, at clauses 8 and 9 of the bill; and the inclusion of efficiencies as a factor when assessing competitive effects for mergers and civil competitor collaborations, at clauses 7 and 10 of the bill.
Beginning with the merger and prohibition provision, Bill would create an arbitrary bright line precluding Canada's Competition Bureau and the Competition Tribunal from evaluating the competitive effects of mergers with a combined market share at or above 60%. The proposal would not take into account or differentiate between any level of increased concentration, even if the acquired target had, for example, a share of 1%.
This would be unprecedented and would make Canada a global outlier. Competition and antitrust laws globally recognize that market share and concentration alone are not themselves determinative of market power and competitive effects. As the Competition Act already recognizes, a conclusion regarding the competitive impact of a merger must evaluate such important factors as the likelihood of entry and expansion, the role played in the market by the acquired entity, the presence of other vigorous and effective competition in a market, and the nature of change and innovation in a market, among other things. In our submission, it would be inappropriate to fetter the ability of the Competition Bureau and the Competition Tribunal to conduct an analysis of market power and competitive effects based on the facts and evidence before them.
Bill 's emphasis on market share and concentration to the exclusion of other factors also presents three further significant problems.
First, the approach would remove entirely the analysis of what matters most, which is competitive conditions pre- and post-merger, in favour of a focus on just market share statistics that are not themselves determinative of market effects.
Second, in many cases a factual conclusion regarding market share cannot be reliably drawn based on a company's current market share.
Third, merging parties frequently do not have the requisite data to determine what their market share is in any relevant antitrust market. The Competition Bureau collects such information as part of its review, but unless the bureau plans to share this information with merging parties or their counsel as part of the enforcement process, which they don't currently do unless required to in litigation, significant due process concerns arise for merging parties.
Turning to the structural presumption provisions, the CBA section does not support the inclusion of structural presumptions in the Competition Act. We agree that concentration and market share levels can provide a useful preliminary screening mechanism to identify potentially problematic mergers. However, we disagree that a merger should be presumed to cause anti-competitive effects on the basis of market share alone.
Further, including structural presumptions in the Competition Act, a statute, will not harmonize Canadian law with U.S. law. This is important. In the U.S., structural presumptions were introduced in non-statutory enforcement guidelines, which are flexible in nature and are preferable to a fixed statute. It's not part of any U.S. legislation. If structural presumptions are introduced, we would submit that the appropriate place to introduce them would be in the Competition Bureau's merger enforcement guidelines, similar to the approach that continues to be taken in the U.S.
Finally, turning now to efficiencies, Bill proposes the inclusion of efficiencies as an explicit statutory factor in sections 93 and subsection 90.1(2) of the Competition Act when assessing whether a merger or a civil competitor collaboration would likely substantially lessen or prevent competition.
The CBA section agrees with this inclusion. It's well recognized in Canada and globally that efficiencies are a relevant factor when assessing competitive effects, because they can result in mergers or competitor collaborations being pro-competitive, enhancing productivity and benefiting consumers. The Competition Bureau has advocated for efficiencies to be among the list of factors that the Competition Tribunal can consider when assessing competitive effects. This change would also reinforce the bureau's current approach when assessing the competitive impact of mergers and civil competitor collaborations, in any event.
Thank you for the opportunity.
:
Thank you to all the witnesses for being here today.
I think, no matter what part of the country you come from, Canadians are wondering, in the context of this legislation, why the heck do I have to pay so much for groceries?
I looked in great detail during the first hour of our meeting today at the Competition Bureau report entitled “Canada Needs More Grocery Competition”. Two key points were sort of addressed that I almost find right now are going to be hard to achieve, and may even be contradictory.
The report outlines, in addition to some other studies conducted by the Competition Bureau, that when the largest firms in an industry consolidate their position, their market share, they are less likely to be replaced or face significant challenges to their market share. The report also notes that we need to encourage growth in the entry of new competitors.
In the context of grocery stores, though, what I essentially read this morning was that the Competition Bureau outlines that it's going to be hard to see competition in our grocery story sector in Canada.
Would that be a fair assumption, Mr. Boswell?
:
What our report outlined were steps the government can take to increase competition in the grocery sector.
I'll give a few examples of addressing restrictive covenants and property controls, which can keep out new entrants across the country.
Another is to draw attention to the benefit of a foreign entrant coming into the Canadian marketplace, as informed by others.
We continue to work with governments to prioritize and get movement on these.
We have since launched an investigation into the use of property controls by the largest grocers as well. There are steps that can be taken to protect and promote competition in the industry, and this is a priority sector for the bureau.
First, we have to recognize that Canada, by population, is small at 40 million; geographically, we are very big.
Our southern neighbour has a big population, big economy, etc., so we are in some sort of a special situation when it comes to allowing, or not allowing, companies to scale up and serve Canadians across this vast country.
Professor Larouche, I'm glad to hear your comments on the length and complexity that is there. The only people who benefit from the complexity are the lawyers, and it just adds to the cost of administering the competition laws in the public sector and in dealing with these big companies.
You also mentioned the institutional framework. I have so many bills regarding this particular issue. Are you suggesting that maybe we should have a totally new bill starting from scratch? It's not as if that were possible, but I'm just saying so.
:
I agree with that approach of keeping the law and the legislation passed through Parliament as nimble as possible, and delegating the authority for the regulation. That can be flexible, depending on the market needs or the changing circumstances.
We are politicians. As political parties, we have to show people that we are working hard for them. Anyway, that is a different thing for a different time.
On the market share, again, I agree with you on keeping up the right number of 30%, 50% or 60%, without recognizing whether it was a vertical merger or a lateral merger, or the nature of the industry and the sector, etc.
Is there anything on the market share that other countries are are doing better and we can adopt?
First, welcome to all of you. It is kind of you to be here today with us.
I want to come back to your testimony, Professor Larouche. We are studying bills here whose purpose is to improve the competition regime, such as Bills and . As you said, there are always additions that seem to have a lot of merit, but they are always minor additions.
What I understand from your testimony is that there are two ways of reforming the Competition Act. The first would be to establish a very clearly defined framework that would give the competition commissioner a lot of latitude, and the second would be to add interminable conditions, which would give the impression of action but would ultimately make the law so complicated it ceased to be functional.
Recently, I spoke with some people about the case of the United States in connection with the structural presumption question. They told me that in the United States there was a presumption in favour of consumers, and that in some cases the competition authorities did not necessarily have to justify their decision to the extent they have to do here in Canada. It would seem that this makes the regime more flexible and faster and reduces the volume of potential appeals, since it provides better protection for consumers. We know that consumers have very diffuse interests, while the interests of corporations, which have resources, are concentrated.
Could this presumption in favour of consumers be adopted into the Canadian competition regime?
I would like this to be clear. What you are discussing in the bills and in this one are largely reforms that are going in the right direction. As you say, the work is being done piecemeal.
Take, for example, the well-known exception for efficiency gains, referred to as the “efficiency gains defence”, which has been abolished. It was created in 1980. In 1980, it came out of the legal literature. It was thought to be a good idea, and it was put into the legislation. It took 30 years, or even 40 years, to get rid of it. In the meantime, everywhere else, it was something that was in the authorities' guidelines. In the 1990s, the idea was added that actually it was all very well to have greater efficiency, but it also had to be proven that consumers would get something out of it at the end of the day.
:
Is my interpretation correct? I am not a lawyer, but I have worked with people in the field of economics and competition in the private sector. I have the impression that there are so many constraints, so many loopholes in the act, that a company with deep pockets to defend itself will ultimately always be able to get around the act as it now stands.
That is the first part of my question. I will give you the rest of my time to answer my questions after.
The second part of my question relates to the 60% market share issue.
I asked Mr. Singh where he came up with the 60% figure. He answered that he had looked at regimes around the world. When asked which ones, he did not know. Ultimately, we see that there are really no 60% cases, 60% is an arbitrary percentage, and ultimately it is better to be consequentialist and try to look at what the effect of a merger would be on the price to consumers: how the efficiency gains would be redistributed.
I have the impression that this is still adding constraints that may again be going to further complicate the regulator's job. Am I right about that?
:
Yes, I would tend to say you are right.
On the first question regarding the behaviour of the corporations, we have to understand that corporations do what they have to do. They have legislation. They hire lawyers and consultants, and they make arguments. The more legislation there is, the more arguments there will be. Especially when it is in the law, judges feel they are able to interpret it. The end result is precisely judgments like Tervita Corporation.
When it is policies of the competition bureau or the authority in place, judges tend to show a certain restraint and give the bureau the benefit of the doubt. I think it is still a good idea to have a balanced law.
On the 60% figure, in the other territories, so that is the European Union and the United States, on the issue of controlling concentrations, they start with tests based on the Herfindahl-Hirschman index, or HHI: all of the concentration indices we have at present or we will have if Bill is passed. Market share does not play an enormous role because it is not a very good indicator.
Thank you to the witnesses for being here.
I notice a difference in tone from my Conservative colleagues. It must be the early morning caffeine injection they had during the previous witness' testimony.
Voices: Oh, oh!
Mr. Brian Masse: I'm glad we are talking about this issue here and appreciate the fact that there have been some changes to the Competition Act over the years. The efficiencies exemption is one that I've been after for a long, long time, and there are others.
We're here, and I think this context is important. I'll ask this question across the board here, maybe starting with Mr. Boswell.
It is correct that this is a very difficult process bringing a private member's bill through. It is one of the tools that's available to us as members of Parliament. As well, we've recently seen that the government did act on changing some legislation, not to the full extent, but here we are with some pros and cons in some of this bill here.
Essentially, the options in front of us right now are either to amend the bill in different aspects and carry on with the work, where there's some good, strong consensus on items, or, alternatively.... Quite frankly, with the date and the things we're looking at, we're probably not going to see other types of changes in the Competition Act for another two to three years. I can't predict the future, but I just don't see that happening given that we have a Parliament whose time frame is winding down right now, given the fact that there will be another electoral call and the fact this committee would have to take this up again.
I'm pleased to hear the competition commissioner's comments about productivity and efficiencies related to regulatory issues—and that's probably a study we could even look at doing—but the chances of our getting to all those things is very, very reduced.
With all that in mind, I'll start with you, Commissioner.
What do we do at this point? Do we look at amending the bill to give extra tools and strengthen competition in Canada right now and work with what we have, or do we wait the time frame that it's going to be and hope, at a bare minimum, that we deal with this years later? That's really kind of where we're at now.
We have the other private member's bill in the Senate, which is great. We don't know what that's going to be, but these are the practical steps that are in front of us to choose from, and those are the paths that we have available to us.
Again, I do take the point that it would be better if a better process were there. While our democracy is one that may fail us in many respects, I still don't know a better process. The alternatives that other places in this world have are not better.
Mr. Boswell, please go ahead, and then we'll go across the witnesses. Please take the time you need. I think we have about four minutes to go.
:
Thank you for that very pragmatic question. I was hoping to have an opportunity to address that head on.
From the Competition Bureau's perspective, as I said in my opening comments, we're really pleased with the attention that's been paid to competition in this private member's bill, and other private member's and government bills to amend the law. I agree with Professor Larouche. It was probably too complex out of the gates in 1986, when it was, some say, drafted by the business community.
In terms of this bill, from the Competition Bureau perspective, I would say that we don't need to address clauses 2, 3, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10 and 11. Clause 4, which deals with the penalty provision for federal financial institutions, is great in terms of the 14 years, but it should be a fine at the discretion of the court—not a maximum fine, the $25 million that it has now.
On clause 12, the bureau believes—and we put this in our recommendations to ISED—that a three-year limitation period for notifiable transactions is a good step forward. Right now, it's only one year. With our colleagues in the United States, there's no limitation period on reviewing mergers.
Finally, with respect to the costs award, that has been addressed in Bill , but I would just point out that in our submission to ISED, we talked about full immunization. Bill C-59 is a pretty reasonable balance so, one way or the other, we're pretty happy with how that comes out. Really, quite strongly, we don't believe that we need those other clauses. They've been addressed in Bill , Bill , and hopefully soon in Bill C-59, but this has been a valuable contribution to the debate and the marketplace of ideas.
:
Okay. We can follow up on this as well.
I guess the point I'm trying to make here is that things moved on as the bill was crafted and created, and that's normal in terms of processes here. It's the same with my position on the tribunal. Going through Bill , I've kept myself open to creating a tribunal for part of it, but from the evidence that's been presented—and we around this table have never really dealt with tribunals before—I've come to some conclusions that give me great concern. Therefore, we left the door open for an amendment to the tribunal, but not to get rid of it. I mean, we could even get rid of the tribunal here, if this body actually chose to do so.
At any rate, that's kind of where we're at. We're in a work-in-progress environment here. I hope we can actually kind of continue to add on while we have the opportunity.
:
I thank the member for his question, Mr. Chair.
If Mr. Généreux agrees, I will answer in English, because there are technical details.
[English]
The combination of the bills that have come in front of this committee, the House finance committee and the Senate over the last several years will, I believe, have an impact in the long term on aspects of competition throughout our economy. It's not going to happen overnight. There's no doubt about that. Also, we don't want to be in the business of over-promising.
However, this country has not paid attention to the importance of competition in the organization of its economic affairs for decades—literally decades. We're a country where we have multiple oligopolies and very significant competitive intensity problems.
This is one important piece to drive competition, which drives down prices, increases consumer choice, drives innovation and drives productivity. Those are the important, long-term benefits of having a country that places importance on competition.
Can it, overnight, fix the affordability crisis we're experiencing? No, and we're not promising that.
However, these are important reforms that turn the ship around. It's a ship that's been sailing since at least 1986.
:
Thank you. It's a brief question.
Commissioner, thank you for coming today. I know you're starting an airline industry study. The public submission deadline is June 17. These are the new powers by Bill , so we're just testing those out.
One concern we have is that there's a letter written by the that says “to focus on domestic...airline services”, not airports. Obviously, we think you should be looking at the whole thing. Airport competition is just as important as the domestic side.
If that comes back, do the powers through Bill allow the to change the course of the study after we've reviewed it or after you've gotten the public consultation on the 17th, yes or no?
:
I do think that this whole-of-government approach I spoke of earlier is something that we as a nation should undertake, with leadership from the federal government. When I talk about that, and when we talk about that at the bureau, it's not like we've created this out of thin air. This is what other countries have done and are doing.
In the 1990s, the Australians had a productivity commission where they examined 1,800 laws and regulations with a view to enhancing competition throughout the Australian economy at the federal level, and the Australian states also participated. It resulted in a significant increase in the Australian GDP of 2.5% as a result of that work. It was worth about 5,000 Australian dollars per household, which was a significant amount of money in the 1990s. There's the Australian example.
The United States currently has a whole-of-government approach to competition in the American economy. There's a White House competition council where all of the secretaries of the various departments in the U.S. government are tasked with identifying competition problems within their areas of remit and fixing them.
We're not talking about something that hasn't been done elsewhere in the world, but it's something we desperately need to get to work on in Canada if we want to solve the problems we have.
:
On clauses 8 and 9, I would think that what is now in Bill with the HHI is good. That's more in line with worldwide standards than market share thresholds, for sure.
As far as clause 3 is concerned, to me, the underlying problem is this need to always choose between sections 45 and 90.1 as a vehicle. That will not be changed. Then it would be a good idea to put some serious sanctions in clause 3 as well, but it will run into problems before the courts, because these are criminal provisions.
If you want to have a level of sanction that matches what is done elsewhere, it should be around 10% as a theoretical maximum. Typically, the authority will go around 4% or 5% of turnover at the level where the profits should be. That's the practice. That would mean, in Canada, if you go by a factor of one to 10 with the EU or the U.S., we would be playing in the $100 million range.
I was not expecting to talk about this, but since Mr. Williams has addressed the subject, I have a question for the commissioner, Mr. Boswell, whom I also want to welcome.
There are three large airports in the Montreal region: one in Saint-Hubert, one in Dorval, and one in Mirabel. One airport authority administers two of those airports, with the result that it has virtually shut one down to travel for the general public, for commercial flights.
This scheme seems to me to have been designed by the federal government to be anti-competitive and to generate anti-competitive behaviour on the part of Aéroports de Montréal.
Is that one of the subjects that interests you, now that you have new investigative powers?
:
I think Mr. Boswell is entirely correct when he talks about the horizontal or transversal approach. There is a huge amount of work to do. The investigative procedure that will be applied for the first time in the airline services industry in Canada should also, if it is used as in the United Kingdom, for example, allow the competition bureau to propose specific recommendations about the regulatory amendments to be made. That is a transversal approach. The competition authority can also point out problems in other sectors.
Apart from all that, a change of mentality is under way. I came back to Canada seven years ago, and I think things are quiet in Canada; the markets are lazy. Take the example of grocery stores, which has been discussed today. We are seeing surprising things there. First, the margins are high. Here, we think a 5% margin is not much. In reality, they are about 2% in the United States and 1% in Europe. So the margin achieved in Canada is very high.
In addition, the major actors here practise identical policies. They all have supermarkets that look like one another. If people complain about prices being too high, they open supermarkets where the range is expanded, with Maxi and Super C, for example. In the United States and Europe, business models are much more diversified.
There are entrants. Whole Foods may position itself in the high-end market. From time to time it will engage in a price war. At the low end, there will be a supermarket with lower prices that will from time to time say it too offers quality. So each supermarket has its own business model and they attack each other.
In these markets, a situation has to be created in which the companies are afraid of what the others are going to do, rather than a situation in which the companies can easily predict what the others are going to do, as is the case here today.